Legal update 17 March 2025

Digital platforms in focus: Antitrust insights from Mainland China and Hong Kong scrutiny of food delivery platform – Part 3

Other Author(s): Marine Zhou of Meng Bo Law Office, a PRC law firm based in Shanghai.

Part 3: Strategic compass: lessons and recommendations for companies operating on the vertical supply chain or managing platform businesses

1. Assessment of market power and impact on the market

Understanding the potential 30% market share threshold

In the Foodpanda/Deliveroo case, one of the conditions to relieve them of their commitments to the Hong Kong Competition Commission (HKCC) is if their respective market share falls below 30%, which would suggest lower market power in a more competitive and fragmented market. This indicates that the HKCC considers that with market share below 30%, vertical restrictions are not presumed illegal under Hong Kong competition rules.

The 30% threshold to some extent aligns with practices in other jurisdictions11:

Cumulative effect of parallel networks will matter

Cumulative foreclosure in vertical agreements can occur even without dominant individual market shares. In the Foodpanda/Deliveroo case, the HKCC noted that smaller platforms faced foreclosure partly because Foodpanda and Deliveroo’s exclusive arrangements collectively controlled a significant share of the market. For instance, in January 2022, about half of the market was tied to their terms.22

This finding aligns with established competition principles. For instance, the EC’s De Minimis Notice—which provides guidance on when agreements are considered to have a negligible effect on competition—sets out that:

  • When both of each party to a vertical agreement have market shares below 15%, their agreement typically has no appreciable effect on competition. However, this threshold drops to 5% when parallel networks of similar agreements exist.33
  • Cumulative foreclosure effects unlikely if less than 30% of the relevant market is affected by such parallel restrictive networks.44

This approach confirms that despite parties to vertical agreements holding moderate market shares (c. 30% or less), foreclosure effects become increasingly probable when these restrictions collectively cover a substantial portion of the market.

Recommendations:
  • Minor to moderate competitor (<30% market share): May impose reasonable restrictions in vertical agreements but should avoid “hardcore” restrictions (e.g. resale price maintenance (unless in exceptional cases), passive-sell bans, wide parity terms). Implement early warning systems if market share nears 25%.
  • Prominent competitor (≥30% market share): Structure restrictions carefully, e.g. limiting duration, removing penalties and ensuring documentation of equal-footing negotiations involving vertical restraints.
  • Cumulative effects: Consider adjusting restrictive terms to mitigate foreclosure risks where such effects of parallel networks reach 30% of the market.

 

2. Strategically navigating vertical exclusive arrangements

Vertical exclusive agreements can create market foreclosure effects, but remedies for addressing these concerns can vary materially based on how competition authorities assess such arrangements.

When unilaterally imposed by a dominant firm or firm with substantial market power

When a dominant firm or a firm with substantial market power unilaterally imposes exclusivity, competition authorities evaluate it under abuse of dominance rules (Article 22 of the Anti-Monopoly Law (AML) in Mainland China; Second Conduct Rule (“SCR”) of the Competition Ordinance (“Ordinance”) in Hong Kong). This typically results in strict enforcement:

  • In the Meituan case, China’s State Administration for Market Regulation (SAMR) prohibited Meituan’s exclusive agreements with restaurants outright.55
  • Similarly, in the recent EU Corning case, Corning offered to remove all exclusivity arrangements to address European Commission concerns.66
When implemented by a non-dominant firm or firm without substantial market power

When firms without dominance implement exclusivity through negotiated agreements (despite potential bargaining power differences), authorities typically assess these under vertical agreement rules (Article 18 of the AML; First Conduct Rule (“FCR”) of the Competition Ordinance):

  • In the Foodpanda/Deliveroo case, the HKCC adopted a more nuanced approach rather than an outright ban77:
  • Since exclusivity in vertical agreements generally is not considered a “hardcore” restriction (with exceptions), there can be greater flexibility to negotiate remedies that address competition concerns while preserving benefits, as shown in the Foodpanda/Deliveroo case.88

A worth-noting point from the Foodpanda/Deliveroo case is that the HKCC reviewed it under the FCR rather than the SCR, despite Foodpanda’s reported 60% market share in mid-2023 – a level that can trigger dominance presumptions in other jurisdictions.99

This approach likely reflects that coverage of the exclusivity schemes did not reach foreclosure levels.1010

HKCC does not deem market share as the only or most significant indicator to assume monopoly market power. Here, Foodpanda and Deliveroo effectively restrained each other’s competitive behaviour to secure exclusive partnerships with restaurants, demonstrating that competition existed between them despite their market positions.1111

Recommendations:
  • Be careful with using penalty schemes: Financial or non-financial penalties can strongly deter counterparties from switching, potentially leading to foreclosure, especially when companies’ market share exceeds 30%.
  • Exclusive arrangement with prominent competitor (>30% Market Share): Exercise caution when implementing exclusivity. If necessary, consider softer measures like shorter contract terms, no switching penalties and shorter notice periods (i.e. generally no more than 2 months) for switching.
  • Adapt to regional antitrust policies: Though the Foodpanda/Deliveroo case set an important precedent in Hong Kong, companies operating across multiple jurisdictions should account for stricter enforcement in certain regions and adjust compliance strategies accordingly.
  • Responding to investigations: When companies’ exclusive vertical agreements are under competition investigations, assessing market positions and the cumulative impact or scope of these agreements will help form a strategic approach to interact with competition authorities.
  • Striving for more balanced remedies: If exclusivity arrangements are assessed under monopoly agreement rules (e.g. FCR of the Ordinance), seek balanced remedies that effectively address competition concerns while protecting reasonable and legitimate business interests.

 

3. Narrow price parity clauses under the microscope

Unlike wide price parity clauses that are generally considered anti-competitive by competition authorities, narrow price parity clauses have received more nuanced treatment.

Some competition authorities found narrow price parity not anti-competitive or even pro-competitive. For example:

  • In HKCC’s 2020 travel agent case, narrow price parity clauses were deemed pro-competitive.1212
  • UK Competition & Markets Authority(“CMA”)’s 2014 private motor insurance case: narrow price parity clauses in this case were found unlikely to impede competition.1313
  • 2015 hotel agent investigations by multi-jurisdictions into Booking.com (“Booking”): France, Italy and Sweden accepted Booking’s commitment to replacing wide price parity with narrow price parity.1414

However, opposition to narrow parity clauses has existed and grown. In the Foodpanda/Deliveroo case, the HKCC found that narrow price parity clauses have actual effects on preventing restaurants from offering better prices on other platforms.

Similarly, Germany’s competition authority banned Booking’s narrow price parity clauses, a decision upheld by German Federal Supreme Court which found the narrow price parity set by Booking restricts the ability of hotels to offer lower prices to consumers who book directly on hotel portals.1515

Last September, the European Court of Justice (ECJ) also delivered a preliminary ruling clarifying that Booking’s price parity clauses (including both wide and narrow price parity) are not objectively necessary for the implementation of Booking’s online hotel booking platform.1616

We consider that differing enforcement stances on narrow parity clauses can be influenced by several factors beyond general variation in competition authorities’ approaches. Key considerations include:

1. Market practice:

The relevance of narrow price parity clauses can depend on how suppliers distribute their products:

  • Suppliers that rely heavily on direct sales (e.g. those with strong brand recognition and customer loyalty) are less affected by narrow parity clauses. Even without such clauses, they are unlikely to offer lower prices on third-party platforms, as direct sales—being their primary channel—are often more profitable.
  • Suppliers that depend more on distributors (e.g. those using third-party platforms as key sales channels) are more constrained by narrow parity clauses. If offering lower prices to certain distributors, they cannot lower prices on their own platforms as they are bound by narrow price parity obligations. In these cases, such clauses can restrict competition by preventing suppliers from undercutting their own direct sales, having an actual effect from wide price parity.

This distinction helps explain different enforcement outcomes in cases such as the UK CMA’s 2014 private motor insurance case and Hong Kong’s Foodpanda/Deliveroo case.

2. Customer behaviour

Consumer habits also play a significant role in the impact of narrow parity clauses:

  • Food delivery platform users tend to stick to one or two platforms since meal prices are relatively more affordable, and the savings from comparing prices across multiple platforms are not significant.
  • Hotel booking platform users, on the other hand, are more likely to compare prices across multiple sites due to the higher cost of accommodations, making it worthwhile to shop for the best deal.

Because food delivery customers are less likely to switch platforms for small savings, restaurants have less incentive to offer lower prices on smaller food delivery platforms than their own sales channel.

Recommendations:
  • Avoid wide price or non-price parity terms: They have been widely recognised as restricting competition by object including the HKCC.
  • Use narrow parity clauses with caution: For smaller players (<30% market share), narrow parity terms are generally low risk. However, as market share grows, the risk of competition concerns increases, requiring careful assessment of their actual effects.
  • Limited justifications for narrow parity clauses: The “preventing free-riding” argument is less convincing to competition authorities, especially for firms with over 30% market share.

 

4. Leveraging global insights for guidance

In the absence of specific rules or guidance in Hong Kong or Mainland China, practitioners and companies often look to competition enforcement practices in other jurisdictions—particularly the EU, and sometimes the UK, US—for insights. This approach was explicitly acknowledged by the HKCC in the Foodpanda/Deliveroo case, demonstrating the HKCC’s openness to considering international precedents when developing its analytical framework.1717

Recommendations:
  • Draw insights from key jurisdictions: Where there is lack of specific local guidance, businesses should stay informed of guidance or practice from other key jurisdictions like the EU, UK and US to help assess potential risks.
  • Watch out to global enforcement trends: Companies operating in Hong Kong should evaluate how similar cases have been treated in more established competition regimes or any actions taken to their international parent or sister companies to make informed decisions on commercial or regulatory-related strategies.
  • Adapt compliance strategies dynamically: As competition law enforcement in Hong Kong evolves, companies should regularly reassess their policies to align with emerging local and global regulatory trends.

 

5. Leveraging defences (e.g. rapidly changing market features) to deal with competition authorities

Digital markets are characterised by rapid change and disruptive innovation. The sudden exit of Deliveroo from the Hong Kong market in April 2025 serves as a stark reminder that even well-established companies can be quickly upended by new competition.1818

This raises crucial questions for future investigations: How can companies leverage market dynamism to their advantage and achieve better outcomes?

EU courts have recognised that in highly innovative markets, traditional indicators like market share provide only a first indicator of market power.1919 Substantial market power indicating market dominance is not static, and its significance varies across industries.2020

This highlights a key takeaway: While high market shares remain a necessary factor in assessing substantial market power or dominance, they are no longer sufficient on their own to establish market power in fast-evolving markets.2121

In the Foodpanda/Deliveroo case, until Keeta entered the Hong Kong market in May 2023, Foodpanda and Deliveroo were the only major players in the online food delivery sector. This led the HKCC to initially view their restrictive practices as potentially foreclosing smaller competitors.

However, Keeta’s expansions during the investigation, eating into the market shares of Foodpanda and Deliveroo, suggested that Deliveroo’s significant market power may have diminished, reducing foreclosure risks. This underscores a vital lesson: companies under investigation should track and document market shifts to demonstrate evolving competitive constraints.

Additionally, the HKCC’s focus on Low Market Share Platforms– those with less than 10% market share – highlights the challenge of fully alleviating concerns. We can infer that the HKCC aims to mitigate foreclosure effects on these smaller platforms and foster competition from them.

In response, companies may consider targeted commitments that address smaller platform concerns without imposing excessive restrictions on themselves or inadvertently benefiting stronger competitors. This approach helps minimise regulatory impact on companies while ensuring a more balanced and efficient investigation process.

Recommendations:
  • Document market dynamism: Proactively track and present evidence of market shifts, including new entrants, changing consumer preferences and technological disruptions. This can help demonstrate that competition is evolving and mitigate regulatory concerns.
  • Track innovation cycles: In fast-moving industries, highlighting shortened product life cycles and frequent technological disruptions can challenge constant market power assessments and support arguments against insurmountable dominance claims.
  • Propose targeted commitments: Identify regulators’ core concerns early and offer narrow and targeted commitments that address these issues without unnecessary obligations.
  • Leverage foreign precedents: Use precedents from other jurisdictions to strengthen arguments. For example, EU courts have recognised that innovation affects market power assessments, which can be used to support similar defences in local investigations.

 

6. Wrapping Up

Vertical restrictions extend beyond online food delivery platforms – they can appear in every platform business or supply and distribution chain in today’s marketplace. While these arrangements often fly under the competition authorities’ radar, certain red flags can quickly bring unwanted scrutiny.

When imposed by market giants, when restrictions blanket significant portions of the market or when measures are designed to restrict competition, antitrust alarms will sound. Recognising this delicate terrain and navigating it carefully is crucial for long-term business success.

 

May be of interest to you:

Digital platforms in focus: Antitrust insights from Mainland China and Hong Kong scrutiny of food delivery platform – A three-part series

Digital platforms in focus: Antitrust insights from Mainland China and Hong Kong scrutiny of food delivery platform – Part 2

Remarks/Footnotes
  1. SAMR, Article 4 of Automotive Industry Antitrust Guidelines, 18 Sep. 2020, at https://www.samr.gov.cn/zw/zfxxgk/fdzdgknr/fldj/art/2023/art_c349cba8055045c197efcef5d84e8182.html; EC, Commission Regulation (EU) 330/2010 (i.e. VBER), which has been renewed by Commission Regulation (EU) 2022/720 on 10 May 2022. See Article 3-5 of VBER, at https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/ALL/?uri=CELEX:32010R0330
  2. HKCC, Online Food Delivery Platforms Case (EC/03JJ), Commission’s Notice of Acceptance, 29 Dec. 2023, p 20, at https://www.compcomm.hk/en/enforcement/registers/commitments/files/OFP_Notice_of_Acceptance_ENG.pdf
  3. EC, Notice on Agreements of Minor Importance Which Do Not Appreciably Restrict Competition Under Article 101(1) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (De Minimis Notice), 30 Aug. 2024, paras 8-10, at https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=planjo:20140708-013.
  4. Id.
  5. SAMR, Decision on Meituan’s Abuse Case in China Online Food & Beverage Delivery Platform Services Case (“Meituan Case”), 8 Oct. 2021, at https://www.samr.gov.cn/fldes/tzgg/xzcf/art/2021/art_eec0e2e8e2e941d6aa607a1b38c9e2d7.html.
  6. Communication from the Commission published pursuant to Article 27(4) of Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 in Case AT. 40728 – Corning, 29 Nov. 2024, at https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52024XC07197
  7. Supra note 2, para 93, and para 97-98. This balanced approach preserves efficiency benefits of exclusive arrangements while mitigating foreclosure effects, addressed HKCC’s concerns from foreclosure.
  8. This is because vertical restraints are generally considered to have pro-competitive effects. Guidelines to FSR, para 6.86 and 6.89; in the EU, exclusive arrangements (subject to certain conditions) can benefit from the Vertical Block Exemption Regulation if the parties to the agreement each hold a market share of 30% or less. See EC, Guidelines on Vertical Restraints (2022/C 248/01), para 120; in the US, the Supreme Court in Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 306–07, recognized that exclusive dealing can be pro-competitive, as it may incentivize retailers to invest in promoting a manufacturer’s products, thereby strengthening interbrand competition at the retail level.
  9. Marketing-Interactive, Survey: KeeTa Captures 43% of HK Market Share in Q1 2024, 08 May 2024. In this report, based on gross merchandise value, Foodpanda had a market share around 62% in Q3 2023. Available at https://www.marketing-interactive.com/survey-keeta-captures-43-of-hk-market-share-in-q1-2024
  10. We may draw reference from US precedents. In U.S. v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001), where exclusive vertical agreements were caught under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, the foreclosure share threshold was suggested as 40-50%. For dominant companies, this threshold is typically lower.
  11. Supra note 2, para 72, “Given their respective strong market positions, each of Foodpanda and Deliveroo appear able to entice partnering restaurants to sign up with them under Exclusive Terms and may compete with each other to obtain Exclusive Terms from such restaurants”.
  12. HKCC, Notice Issued Under Section 2 of Schedule 2 of the Competition Ordinance Regarding the Commission’s Proposal to Accept Commitments in Online Travel Agents Case (EC/02NJ), 13 May 2020, fn 2, at https://www.compcomm.hk/en/enforcement/consultations/past_consultations/files/OTA_Notice_ENG.pdf
  13. CMA, Private Motor Insurance Market Investigation, 24 Sep. 2014, p 8-15 – 8-17, at https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/5421c2ade5274a1314000001/Final_report.pdf
  14. Booking, Booking.com to Amend Parity Provisions Throughout Europe, 25 Jun. 2025, at https://news.booking.com/en/bookingcom-to-amend-parity-provisions-throughout-europe/
  15. German Federal Supreme Court, Case KVR 54/20 – Booking.com, para 12, 18 May 2021, at https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Publikation/EN/Others/BGH_Entscheidung_Booking_EN.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=1
  16. Judgment of the Court in Case C-264/23, see reasoning from para 59 to 72, at https://curia.europa.eu/juris/document/document.jsf?text=&docid=290211&pageIndex=0&doclang=EN&mode=req&dir=&occ=first&part=1&cid=19880778
  17. Supra note 2, para 111 and its ft, and para 133.
  18. Deliveroo, Deliveroo Exits Hong Kong, 10 Mar. 2025, at https://ir.design-portfolio.co.uk/viewer/79/75092
  19. EU, General Court, Case T-342/07, Ryanair v Commission EU:T:2010:280, para 56.
  20. Case 85/76, Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v Commission, ECLI:EU:C:1979:36, para 40.
  21. Thibault Schrepel, A Systematic Content Analysis of Innovation in European Competition Law, European Journal of Law and Economics 58, 355–395 (2024).
Subscribe

Follow our insights

Sign up for regular updates covering the latest news, regulations and case law relevant to your business.
View more

Please scan the QR code and follow us on WeChat

Wechat ID: JSM_Legal
JSM WeChat QR code